Relative price changes are the catalyst for the substitution effect. When faced with a price change of one good relative to a related good, consumers typically seek to maximize their utility (i.e., satisfaction) from adjusting their consumption choices. They will tend to substitute extra consumption of the relatively cheaper good in place of the relatively more expensive good.
This adjustment occurs while holding the total level of satisfaction (i.e., utility) constant.
Note that I pointed out that the substitution effect applies between related goods. For example, if the price of coffee increases while tea stays the same, it is likely that consumers will substitute more tea for less coffee. However, a rise in the price of coffee is unlikely to have any direct substitution effect on the demand for crude oil, cinema tickets, football boots, or any other types of unrelated products.
Nevertheless, since incomes are constrained, any increase in expenditure on one good must necessarily also have an impact on other goods, related or not.
The strength of the substitution effect can vary depending on several factors. One crucial factor is the availability and accessibility of substitute products. If there are numerous substitute products readily available in the market, consumers are more likely to switch to a lower-priced alternative when the price of a particular product increases.
The level of brand loyalty to a given product can also impact the strength of the substitution effect. If a consumer has a strong attachment to a particular brand or product, they may be less likely to switch to a substitute, even if the price is significantly lower.
Timeframe is also an important consideration because consumers do not immediately adjust their spending patterns when the price of certain goods change. For some goods, prices are very responsive in the short-term, but for other goods it takes more time to adjust. See the real world examples below for more information on this.
In the substitution effect graph below, I have illustrated how a consumer changes his/her preferred combinations of goods x and y. For an explanation of how this graph works, you can read my articles about the Budget Line and the Indifference Curve.
The initial preferred bundle of goods occurs where the highest possible indifference curve (U) just touches the budget line (BL). At this point, the consumer purchases x,y amounts as indicated by the dotted lines.
Now, after the price of good x falls, the consumer purchases much more of it, and actually reduces consumption of good y in order to be able to further increase consumption of good x. The new preferred consumption bundle occurs at x',y'.
There are two effects at work here, one is the substitution effect and the other is called the income effect.
The substitution effect tends to work in conjunction with the income effect, because when the price of one product changes relative to a related product, it will affect total purchasing power of a given income (or budget constraint).
For example, when the price of coffee falls, consumers will tend to consume more of it instead of alternative beverages, but they may also have some spare income remaining that can be spent on other goods & services. For more details about this, see my article:
The extent to which each effect dominates the other depends entirely on the nature of the good itself. For details on this, see my article about Types of Economic Goods, and especially about Complementary Goods & Substitute Goods
The substitution effect is not merely an abstract concept in economics; it has real-world implications and applications that affect both individual consumers and entire markets. Here are some practical examples of how the substitution effect manifests in various economic scenarios.
While the substitution effect is a valuable tool for analyzing consumer behavior and market dynamics, it is not without its limitations and criticisms. The following limitations and criticisms are applicable:
Related Pages: