The price elasticity of demand relates to a product (a good or service) and its demand sensitivity to changes in its price. In other words, it measures the amount by which consumers will adjust how much of the product they will want to purchase as its price increases or decreases.
We know from the first law of demand that, at higher prices, consumers will demand a lower quantity of a normal good (and vice versa for lower prices). But the price elasticity of demand goes further than this and calculates the extent of those movements in demand.
For some products, a change in price brings a larger change in demand than it does for others, and this should be intuitively obvious with a little thought. If the price of basic necessities increases, our demand for these products is more or less unchanged because we have to have them. Other goods are more dispensable, and so our demand for them is more sensitive to price changes.
Time is another consideration when thinking about the price elasticity of demand for a product, because we may be able to react to some changes over the long-term that we can’t really do much about in the short-term, or vice-versa.
There are several factors that influence the price elasticity of demand for a product:
Yes, in fact it is always negative for normal goods since any increase in price always leads to a decrease in quantity demanded. There are some exceptions, but these apply to different types of economic goods i.e. Giffen Goods and Veblen goods, where demand actually increases as price increases.
In the graph below I have illustrated a typical demand curve for a product. It is downward sloping indicating the inverse relationship between price and quantity. It displays one portion of the curve that has inelastic demand, and another that has elastic demand. Inelastic demand occurs at quantities below 25, and elastic demand occurs at quantities above 25.
Inelasticity at lower quantities relates to the relative scarcity that occurs at lower amounts, and increased reluctance to give up more of the product. In this sense, as the slope of the demand curve gets steeper, demand becomes more inelastic. However, slope alone is insufficient to determine elasticity, for that we need to consider total expenditure (see below).
The price elasticity of demand is defined as the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price. The formula for this is:
PED = %ΔQ / %ΔP
The triangle Δ is used to denote ‘change’. Depending on the value of PED, demand for a product can be classified into different categories:
Another, simpler method, that defines elasticity is given by what happens to total expenditure as the price of a product changes. Table 1 below categorizes these movements, but it fails to give a specific value (or coefficient) that measures the extent of elasticity or inelasticity. I’ll show how to calculate the price elasticity of demand coefficient in a section below.
The Isoelastic demand graph illustrates a curve with unit elastic demand i.e., where any change in price is matched by an equal offsetting change in quantity demanded, such that total expenditure is unchanged.
Unit elasticity of demand is, of course, more of a theoretical concept rather than a common occurrence in the real world. However, it does help us to think about elasticity in a more robust way.
As mentioned above, it is not the case that elasticity depends on slope alone, we also have to consider how expenditure changes. We can have a demand curve that is price elastic along its entire curve, and we can have a demand curve that is inelastic along its entire curve, or even unit elastic as in the graph above.
As can be seen on the left-side of the graph below, perfectly inelastic demand means that any change in price at all has no effect on the quantity demanded i.e. consumers regard it as an essential item. Since the change in quantity is zero, dividing that by any price change is also zero, meaning that perfectly inelastic demand has a coefficient of zero.
On the right-side of the graph above, perfectly elastic demand means that any increase in the prevailing price will be met with a total loss of demand. This means that, with a zero change in price, the quantity change divided by zero gives an infinite elasticity coefficient.
There are two standard approaches to calculating the price elasticity of demand depending on whether we are looking at a particular point on the relevant demand curve, or over a range of that curve.
Point elasticity of demand is illustrated on the left-side of the graph below. I’ve shown two different points on the demand curve for a given product. At point A demand is relatively more inelastic than at point B (we can see this due to the steeper slope of the curve at that point). We cannot calculate the point elasticity without an equation that defines the demand curve but, if we had that equation, we could use a technique in calculus called differentiation to work it out.
On the right-side of the graph above I have again illustrated the same two points, A and B, and I have drawn a single line that passes through those points. We can use a method called the ‘arc elasticity of demand’ (also known as the midpoint formula) to give a single measure of elasticity between these two points. We do this with the following formula:
ARC PED = (ΔQ/ΔP) (P*/Q*)
P* and Q* are the average prices and quantities for points A and B.
This works out as:
(3/-$13)($15.50/3.5) or -.23*4.43 = -1.02
As is the convention, we ignore the negative sign and simply conclude that the arc elasticity of demand coefficient over this range is 1.02, which is slightly elastic. We can check this with table 1 above to see what happened with total expenditures.
At point A there was a total expenditure of $44 while at point B this rose slightly to $45. Table 1 shows that when price decreases (as it did from point A to point B) an increase in total expenditure indicates elastic demand.
The price elasticity of demand coefficient gives a simple number that economic agents can use to assess how responsive total expenditure is to price changes. This information has obvious value to producers who will want to estimate the demand for their goods and services at different price points, but it has other uses too, especially for government policy makers.
PED plays a vital role in various economic and business decisions.
How does consumer psychology influence Price Elasticity of Demand?
Consumer perceptions of value, brand loyalty, and psychological pricing (e.g., $9.99 vs. $10.00) can affect PED. Strong brand attachment can make demand less elastic, while price-sensitive consumers may exhibit higher elasticity.
How do businesses test the Price Elasticity of Demand for their products?
Companies use A/B testing, historical sales data analysis, demand forecasting models, and price experimentation to determine how sensitive consumers are to price changes.
How does PED interact with Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand (XED)?
XED measures how the demand for one product changes in response to the price change of another. Complementary goods (e.g., coffee and sugar) and substitute goods (e.g., Coke vs. Pepsi) influence each other’s elasticity.
How do international trade and exchange rates affect PED?
A weaker currency makes imports more expensive, affecting demand elasticity for foreign goods. Export demand elasticity determines how responsive foreign buyers are to price changes due to currency fluctuations.
What is the relationship between PED and consumer income levels?
Higher-income consumers may exhibit more inelastic demand for luxury goods, while lower-income consumers are more sensitive to price changes in essential goods. This ties into income elasticity of demand (YED), which measures how demand changes with income fluctuations.
Can PED change over time for the same product?
Yes. Over time, consumers may find substitutes or adapt their behavior. For example, Gasoline demand is inelastic in the short term but more elastic in the long run as people switch to fuel-efficient cars or public transport.
Price Elasticity of Demand helps measure how sensitive consumer demand is to changes in price. Various factors influence elasticity, including the availability of substitutes, whether a good is a necessity or a luxury, the time frame considered, and how much of a consumer’s income is spent on the product.
PED can be classified into different types, from perfectly inelastic to perfectly elastic, and has many real-world applications in business pricing strategies, government taxation, and policy decisions.
Related Pages: