Economists sometimes use the term excess demand to describe a situation of disequilibrium in the market for a particular good or service. In most situations this is nothing to be concerned about, because is just a temporary phenomenon that will quickly auto-resolve itself as via the forces of supply and demand and the price mechanism.
The excess demand meaning (which is sometimes called unsatisfied demand) is that there is a potential profit opportunity for any firm that can increase supply to meet that demand.
For example, if prices are too low for a product, there will be more demand from customers wishing to purchase that product than suppliers can accommodate. This excess demand, will soon create shortages of that product, and producers will respond to that by raising both prices and output until supply equals demand and equilibrium is reached.
In the graph below I have illustrated a market that is in equilibrium. At a price of p* the market clears at a quantity of q*, there is no excess supply or demand, and both buyers and sellers are satisfied.
I've illustrated the concept of consumer surplus and producer surplus in the graph because, as I'll show below, these are affected when there is unsatisfied demand in the market.
Consumer surplus is illustrated by the blue triangle below the demand curve and above the market price. The surplus here is gained by all those consumers who purchased the product at price p* even though many of them would have been prepared to pay more.
This occurs because each customer values goods differently even though everyone pays the same price (assuming that there is no price-discrimination in the market).
The same reasoning applies to producer surplus. Each seller receives the same price of p* even though some sellers would have been prepared to sell for a lower price. Producer surplus is illustrated by the green area below the price and above the supply curve.
Next we'll consider what happens to price and quantity when the government decides to intervene in the market to restrict the price. Examples of excess demand resulting from price restriction policies are commonplace, with most typically being used in times of economic upheaval.
In this graph the supply and demand curves are exactly the same as before, and the equilibrium price and quantity would again be p* and q* if left to market forces.
However, suppose that the government is unhappy with the market price and decides to restrict it in order that it can become more affordable for consumers. The government fixes the price at Pf, a price at which consumers would like to increase their purchasing of the product all the way up to a new quantity of q.
Unfortunately for those consumers, producers are not so happy with the new price as it reduces their ability to make a profit. At a price of Pf, producers will only be willing to supply a quantity of qf which, contrary to the hopes of consumers, is actually lower than the original quantity of q*.
The difference between the quantity that consumers demand, and the quantity that producers are prepared to supply, gives us the excess demand measure (illustrated by the yellow arrows, and equal to q - qf).
Sticking with the excess demand graph analysis, we can clearly see from the graph that there have been changes to the surpluses gained by consumers and producers as a result of the price fixing. We can even use the graph to assess whether or not society as a whole has gained or lost out from the government intervention.
Consumer surplus seems to have done okay, it has been reduced by the red area DWL 1, which is the deadweight loss for consumers, but it has grown by the gray area. Remember that consumer surplus occurs above the price but below the demand curve, meaning that some of the original producer surplus has been transferred to consumers, as shown by the gray area.
Producer surplus has been reduced dramatically, not only do they lose surplus as shown by the red deadweight loss area DWL 2, they have also lost the gray surplus area.
Overall, we can clearly see that society is worse off because of the two red DWL areas. This constitutes a net loss to society because neither consumers nor producers can capture this lost surplus at the new lower fixed price, even though it was originally being captured by the market when it was in equilibrium, before the unfortunate government intervention.
It may occur to some readers that, so long as consumers are better off, who cares about producers? The answer is that even consumers ultimately lose out. It is, of course, all well and good for those consumers who manage to obtain the products they desire at the fixed lower price, but for many consumers those products simply will not be available (or if they are they may only be available on a black-market at much higher prices).
The shortages that arise from excess demand at the lower price are a real problem for all consumers if the product is something that is essential, and needed on a frequent basis. In this case, even those customers who were initially lucky enough to obtain goods, will soon face problems obtaining them in subsequent shopping attempts.
Many excess demand examples (resulting from fixed prices) can be found in the former USSR economies, where everyday food items were simply unavailable during the communist era. People would line up for hours at a time trying to obtain bread from bakeries and shops, only to be met with with bare shelves. It's a common misconception in the west that the people of those countries had no money, they did have money, they just couldn't use it to buy enough of the goods that they needed.
Ongoing supply line difficulties associated with the global pandemic give us another example, because it is causing some resurgence of government price control policies, as explained in this article by 'The Conversation'.
As Milton Friedman noted:
"We economists don't know much, but we do know how to create a shortage."
The point in both of these examples of excess supply is that the shortage problems they create can apply to more or less all products throughout the entire economy, and not just to specific products or industries. Shortages of any given product are much less of a problem because there will likely be a plentiful supply of a substitute good that can be purchased instead.
When shortages occur for lots of different products then it will likely put pressure on inflation to increase, or for goods to be sold on a black market thereby evading official price controls.
The rationing of products that existed during and after World War 2 came with severe disruption to the forces of supply and demand and, sure enough, black markets soon emerged to facilitate trade. The extent to which the authorities were aware of these markets, and simply tolerated them, or were unaware is debatable. In either case the result creates many problems, and it is to be hoped that such price controls can be avoided in future.
In elementary economics you may come across problems that ask you to calculate excess demand given two simple functions. These functions, for supply and demand, are typically expressed as linear equations of the form Y = MX + C. For example, suppose that supply and demand are given as:
To find the equilibrium price you simply need to the value of 'p' where supply equals demand. This is where 2p+80 = 100-3p and some simple algebra reduces this to 5p = 20 (i.e., add 3p to both sides of the equals sign, and deduct 80 from both sides). Then simply divide both sides by 5 to get the equilibrium price of p = 4.
You can prove this by substituting 4 into the supply and demand functions above to verify that you arrive at equal an equal quantity supplied and demanded:
So, supply equals demand at an equilibrium price of 4 and quantity of 88.
Now, if the market price is fixed below 4, say at p = 3, then there should be some excess demand. Working through the functions again gives:
Clearly this is not an equilibrium point and there is unsatisfied demand of 91 - 86 = 5.
The extent to which demand will continue to exceed supply in the long run will depend upon how long it takes the government to allow the equilibrium price to be restored. Any permanent fix that prevents the equilibrium price from clearing the market will likely lead to an illegal black market (sometimes called an informal market) where goods can be bought and exchanged behind the back of the authorities.
The need for a black market will emerge because people are resourceful and wherever there is unsatisfied demand for a product there will be an opportunity for profits to be made if new supply can be brought to market for sale. Black markets nearly always develop during times of rationing and price controls, and it is likely that we will again witness these things if our governments adopt incomes policies and price controls in the battle against inflation.
Related Pages: